*{TRADING TO COMPETE AND COMPETING TO TRADE - A BIAC Discussion Note on the Interaction between Two Policy Fields - Introduction} 1. Trade officials are experiencing a challenging decade in the 1990s. No sooner had they laboured to complete the Uruguay Round than a series of complex trade policy linkages were proposed for the new WTO's agenda. As a result, trade interactions with environment, labour standards and competition are now being analysed and debated in the OECD and other international fora prior to being discussed at the WTO. The issues are generally not new, but increasing trade liberalisation combined with the fast pace of globalisation has raised certain questions about whether, and if so how, the WTO or other international organisations should take account of these distinct policy objectives in international markets. This paper provides BIAC's views on what is perhaps the most challenging -- and important -- linkage for international business: trade and competition. 2. The topics of convergence and comity in international markets are a central focus of competition policy in all leading industrial countries, and the OECD is to be commended for according it a high level of attention. Although there have been several attempts to deal with the international trade effects of certain restrictive business practices including notably, but not exclusively, cartels, the present climate has resulted in a number of conflicts which have been difficult to resolve and which demonstrate the desirability of, if not need for, broader engagement. BIAC believes the OECD should build on its voluntary recommendations and previous analysis of this complex field to develop a foundation for increasing cooperation and possibly, in time, a framework for multi- or plurilateral accords. In this regard, BIAC welcomes the OECD's initiative to study the issue of market contestability. *partie=titre Key Issues *partie=nil 3. The trade/competition policy interface involves a range of business situations and arrangements which may be increasingly common in a globalised economy, but which present government officials with some very sensitive issues. As background for discussion, the following is a brief description of certain examples. 4. Horizontal agreements: The clearest examples of this type of arrangement affecting cross-border trade and competition are export cartels. In this case, a number of large producers from one country may enter into an agreement which sets prices or output levels for foreign markets. While domestic cartel behaviour may be illegal under most national competition laws, governments have been or may be tempted to "turn a blind eye" towards cartels which have their main effect outside national borders. Such arrangements may even be acceptable to the importing governments if they are part of a voluntary export restraint (VER). Still, export cartels may have anti-competitive effects on the importing market(s), and on the exporting market(s) for those companies that are not party to the agreement. The situation becomes less clear if, for example, a number of small and/or medium-sized producers enter into an agreement to reap efficiency gains in export markets which they would not have by themselves. Such arrangements may not have anti-competitive effects in the global, regional or even large foreign national markets, but they may cause trade frictions with smaller countries. The current difficulty for national government officials is that the domestic or international effects of such cartels may be interpreted and/or enforced differently leading to trade frictions. 5. Vertical agreements: These arrangements describe special and sometimes exclusive relationships along the production-distribution chain, such as between manufacturers and retailers or material providers and assemblers. Generally, such agreements can have anticompetitive effects if exclusive dealing and other restrictive arrangements unduly restrict market entry by domestic or foreign products and/or result in artificial price maintenance. On the other hand, vertical agreements (e.g., through franchising) can also increase competition by facilitating market entry for products or by fostering efficiencies which result in greater horizontal competition. Similar to horizontal arrangements, the determination of whether vertical agreements are pro- or anti-competitive, may be a matter of different interpretations by both companies and governments, leading to trade frictions. 6. A related issue to both horizontal and vertical arrangements involves the trend for firms to enter into joint ventures/strategic alliances for research and development, production, marketing and distribution of a product or service. While such arrangements can generally be considered pro-competitive if they produce efficiency gains, they may also be anti-competitive if, as a result of the agreement, the parties to an alliance are able to exercise excessive control over a product or service market. Here again, different interpretations may lead to trade frictions. 7. *partie=titre Abuse of dominant positions: *partie=nil A major concern in national (or regional) competition policy is the actual (or potential) abuse of market power by dominant enterprises. Such abuse could be manifested, for example, by a large company using predatory pricing to drive its smaller competitors out of a particular market. The potential for abuse is a significant consideration in the scrutiny of mergers to determine whether they could result in excessive market power or its exercise. The interpretation of what constitutes a dominant position, or a particular abuse of such a position, can be a matter of a considerable complexity in a domestic market. The issue is even more complicated if the alleged abuse involves foreign or international markets. In this case, different approaches of analysis, interpretation and/or means of enforcement among the various competition (and trade) authorities can lead to considerable friction. 8. *partie=titre Public involvement: *partie=nil A broad area of potential trade conflicts involve government actions which pose risks to domestic or foreign market access. Such state involvement might include certain trade measures (e.g., VERs, etc.) or competition-related actions such as sanctioning public or regulated private monopolies, creating favourable conditions for state-owned companies, providing subsidies and other state aid to local private companies, giving preferential consideration for government procurement, tolerating restrictive business practices, etc. These are particularly difficult issues for trade and competition officials because such public involvement is generally considered to be a sovereign prerogative and the necessity or desirability of government participation in the economy is clearly a matter of local interpretation. Yet significant public participation can clearly restrict market entry and competition from companies without the benefit of such support, and also create tensions among trading partners. *partie=titre Principal Challenges for Policy Makers *partie=nil 9. The above examples serve as a general description of some of the main issues confronting policy-makers and businesses. From this brief survey, there are clearly a number of key policy problems which must eventually be addressed in any multilateral (or plurilateral) solution to the trade/competition policy interface. For the most part, these issues are welldocumented by the OECD and various experts. 10. *partie=titre Problems of jurisdiction: *partie=nil Questions of jurisdiction, as well as the parallel issues of moderation and restraint, underly much of the debate on the interaction between trade and competition policies. The issue involves both the application of national competition policies to foreign situations or actions which have an impact on local competition, as well as whether, and if so how, trade and competition officials should take each others' policy objectives into consideration. The OECD has already undertaken considerable analysis and held numerous discussions on this issue. Moreover, the 1986 OECD Recommendations have proven effective in promoting consultation between its Members on issues of bilateral concern. However, BIAC believes that the current trend in international economic relations is for increasingly complex issues which will require further cooperation on jurisdiction among sovereign states. The 1995 OECD Recommendation, which strengthens Member countries' endorsement of comity and offers the CLP Committee as a facilitator in conciliation, is a very positive contribution. 11. *partie=titre Problems of interpretation: *partie=nil Many of the examples mentioned above pose problems as a result of differences of interpretation between competition authorities, or between competition and trade officials. The OECD's efforts to promote mutual understanding and convergence in Members' competition policies have made and are making an invaluable contribution to better cooperation in the field. Similarly, discussions of important issues within OECD's Working Group on Trade and Competition are undoubtedly making progress in promoting better understanding between policy fields. BIAC believes the OECD should continue to strive for a common understanding of basic core principles for use on issues involving trade and competition policy. The "Indicative Checklist for the Assessment of Trade Policy Measures" appended to the 1986 Recommendation on areas of potential conflict between competition and trade policies provides a good foundation for common understanding. However, the resolution of future problems would benefit from further agreement on certain core criteria for the application of competition policies. 12. *partie=titre Problems of approach: *partie=nil Related to the need for better mutual understanding of the issues addressed by competition and trade officals, there are also clear frictions which result from the basically different approaches used in the two policy fields. BIAC believes that the OECD should build on its previous work on this issue with a view towards furthering understanding, if not eventual implementation, of common approaches to situations involving both trade and competition concerns. 13. *partie=titre Problems of dispute resolution: *partie=nil The OECD has already undertaken considerable analysis of this issue, and has attempted to provide a mechanism to diffuse conflicts from the extraterritorial application of competition laws through various instruments, including the 1986 (and 1995) Recommendations referred to previously. While the Recommendation concerning cooperation between Member countries on restrictive business practices affecting international trade has been an effective outlet for notification and consultation among competition authorities, the provisions for conciliation have (apparently) not been tested. The important question is whether international economic relations would benefit from a better procedure for the arbitration of disputes between governments in the trade/competition interface. Possibly in time the WTO can play a role. For the immediate future, voluntary consultation through the OECD seems more likely to be effective. *partie=titre Proposals for Discussion *partie=nil 14. There have been a number of proposals made for improving the interaction between trade and competition policies. For example, in 1993 a group of experts prepared a far-reaching "Draft International Anti-trust Code as a GATT-MTO-Plurilateral Trade Agreement", which was presented to and discussed with members of the OECD CLP Committee. Many interesting ideas were also suggested and discussed at the 1994 OECD Roundtable on New Dimensions of Market Access in a Globalising World Economy. Most recently, the European Commission Group of Experts submitted an interesting report on "Competition in the New Trade Order: Strengthening International Competition and Rules". 15. The OECD Committees on Trade and Competition Law and Policy have been continuing to discuss ways and means of improving cooperation and understanding between their respective fields, and OECD Ministers gave new impetus to this work at their 1995 Council Meeting. BIAC agrees that it is necessary to take some concrete steps and provides below four proposals for OECD Ambassadors' consideration. 16. The OECD should continue its efforts to promote convergence in the implementation of Member countries' competition policies. Because national differences in the application and enforcement of competition policies may be significant obstacles to meaningful international cooperation, further progress on convergence must be considered a priority for the OECD. BIAC has participated in many of the discussions on this complex topic with the OECD Competition Law and Policy Committee, particularly the important work on merger control procedures, and we would be pleased to contribute to even greater efforts in this area. 17. Since exemptions from domestic competition laws can be a significant source of trade frictions, the OECD CLP Committee could seek to develop a common understanding of minimum criteria for the existence of such exemptions and state restraints. Such a "checklist" would thus extend beyond local efficiency considerations to include issues concerning the potential impact on competition both in domestic and foreign markets. An agreed set of considerations may serve to pre-empt future conflicts or, at a minimum, provide support for the initiation of positive comity procedures. 18. The OECD could further study the relationship between barriers to entry and effective competition. An important goal of strong, national antitrust enforcement is consumer welfare. This goal is best served by markets which are not blocked or otherwise distorted by private or governmental restraints of trade. Thus, while the chief goal of antitrust is not market access by foreign competitors, open markets and consumer welfare are distinctly related. BIAC recommends that the OECD CLP Committee study this relationship together with the Trade Committee in the context of its market contestability project. 19. As a corollary to this recommendation, the OECD could consider how certain competition principles might be used in the determination of whether trade measures should be applied. Although this issue may be addressed in the market contestability project, the OECD CLP Committee should also study the matter, possibly through the analysis and discussion of test cases under the 1986 Recommendation for cooperation between Member countries in areas of potential conflict between competition and trade policies. *{Conclusion} 20. BIAC supports the OECD's work to promote international cooperation on the linkage between trade and competition policies. The international business community clearly has a strong interest in the success of these efforts because if, as a speaker at a 1994 OECD Conference on Market Access said, "firms trade to invest and invest to trade", it is even more true that firms trade to compete and compete to trade. 21. The issues are admittedly very complex for both governments and business, involving sensitive questions about sovereign rights and private business conduct. However, OECD Member governments and business recognised long ago that competition does not stop at national borders -- a fact which is even more true today as a result of the continuing globalisation process. 22. It is therefore crucial that international economic relations eventually encompass a framework for resolving conflicts between competition and trade policies. The OECD includes the major trading nations of the world, all 25 of which have competition laws. BIAC believes the OECD should thus bear a primary responsibility for building on its past work in this area to develop effective means for dealing with this important policy challenge. As the officially recognised consultative body representing the OECD business community, BIAC is fully prepared to participate in this process.