*{M I G R A T I O N A N D G L O B A L I S A T I O N The new slaves July 1998 PREFACE Globalisation has led to unprecedented levels of migration. The ILO estimates there are more than 42 million migrant workers worldwide. An accurate estimate is difficult to arrive at, however, and the ILO figure does not take into account the millions of illegal migrants. Nor should the scale of international migration allow us to forget the internal movements within countries, for which figures are rarely recorded. China alone has 80 million internal economic migrants. How are these migrant flows organised? What are the main motives, how have they developed? It is the aim of this study to answer these questions, as it seeks to unravel the complex ties between migration and globalisation. As the circulation of goods and capital accelerates, the circulation of the workforce increases apace. With the accent on maximum flexibility, labour is a commodity like any other. The availability of millions of workers, as a result of growing pauperisation, meets the employers demand for a mobile and highly flexible workforce. The great majority of these migrants are low-skilled or unskilled workers. Women now make up a growing proportion of migrant workers. There are nearly half a million Sri Lankan women emigrants in the Middle East, and 12 women for every man among the inter-Asian migrants from the Philippines. The increasing flow of women economic migrants is also less predictable and harder for the State to control. There is a tendency, notes the study, towards more temporary migration, with repeated movements which provide rich pickings for the recruitment and placement agencies. In Asia for example, such agencies manage about 80 per cent of migration to the Gulf States. The agencies are also used by those who wish to migrate permanently, but illegally. Some of these enterprises are organised. Others amount to one or two smugglers. Many flirt with illegality, and rely on the complicity of civil servants to ensure impunity, with all the abuses which that implies. There are countless cases of illegal migrants crammed into the hold of a boat, or abandoned by the roadside, promised jobs that don’t exist (or turn out to be a life of prostitution), of exorbitant prices that leave the migrants in debt and forced into illegality, of confiscated passports… ”But with no visa and no money, many potential migrants have no choice but to turn to these modern-day slave traders.” There is also a heavy personal price to pay for migration. “Qualitatively, the material constraints linked to emigration often lead to a break-up of family life, which is felt particularly acutely when it is the woman who leaves”, explains journalist André Linard, who wrote the report. For the country of origin, it represents a loss of human and financial resources. But it also represents a not inconsiderable source of currency entering the country, and a painless way of reducing unemployment statistics. Sometimes the money sent home by migrants to their families constitutes the country’s primary source of income, as in El Salvador for example. In other countries, such as Cuba, emigration helps relieve the social tensions created by unemployment and the lack of future prospects. Aware of these potential advantages, many countries are competing fiercely on the migrant labour market, all to the benefit of the employers, but to the detriment of the workers, who are traded like mere commodities. In the host countries the migrant workers are the perfect scapegoats, as was dramatically demonstrated by the recent Asian crisis which led to hundreds of thousands of migrants abruptly being sent home like unwanted goods to their own country. Although several studies show that migrants contribute more to their host country than they cost them, host country nationals frequently accuse them of “stealing the bread from their mouths” and treat them like second class citizens - with the same obligations but not the same rights as national citizens, particularly in terms of social security. The ICFTU study points to the contradiction between the economic motives that favour migration and the cultural and political rejection faced by all too many migrants. Low paid jobs, difficult working conditions, discrimination of all kinds… in both North and South, migration is frequently synonymous with exploitation, particularly for the most vulnerable groups. Domestic workers are a case in point, made all the more vulnerable by their isolation, their direct dependence and their constant presence at the workplace. Many cases of extreme exploitation have recently made the headlines. From the networks of deaf and dumb Mexicans in New York to the maids in the Persian Gulf, via the clothing sweatshops in the Parisian suburbs, the dramatic stories relayed in the press have shown how illegality leads to even greater exploitation. How can migrant workers be defended? The ICFTU study lists the existing legal instruments, but stresses that they are rarely enforced, if at all. That is why the trade unions, who believe migrant workers should be treated like any other worker, with exactly the same rights, are pressing at the national and international level for the application of these legal instruments. At the same time they try to assist the migrants on the spot. Whether in the United States, with Mexican seasonal agricultural workers, or in Belgium, the Netherlands or Italy with mainly North African migrant workers, trade unions have frequently taken action to assist migrant workers. At every level, the trade unions’ principal objective is clear: to organise solidarity. In the age of the international market, the balance of power is also international, and industrial relations are no exception. The business community has understood that for a long time, and the trade unions are striving to organise solidarity on a far more international basis with all those pursuing the same objectives. Their aim is to ensure that the boom in the international labour market does not turn against those most concerned, the migrant workers. The study comes at a perfect time for ensuring a better understanding of the migratory process, particularly given that the gap between rich and poor continues to grow, not only between North and South, but between the regions of the South. Individuals or whole communities have always been on the move, long before national borders were invented. The reasons were manifold: conflict and war, natural phenomena, too many people for too few resources… people have moved to such an extent that virtually no one group can claim to have historically “pure” roots. Today, population groups and, above all, individuals, continue to move across or within national borders. They may do so for political reasons (war, conflict, threats… ), to escape natural disasters (drought, cyclones… ) or for economic motives (jobs, the chance to make a living). So what’s new? The economy has “globalised”, and migration has intensified: the free circulation of capital and goods has been accompanied by the more or less free circulation of persons (despite much resistance). Furthermore, it is the first time 1 that labour has migrated in such large numbers to meet the demand of potential employers; it is a sign that the labour force is considered as a commodity like any other. International migration and globalisation are linked, therefore, but the relationship is not necessarily straightforward. It is the different aspects of this socio-economic relationship that this study sets out to examine, from the workers’ perspective.2 The conclusions do not all lead in the same direction. For example, while it is true that globalisation has intensified the migration of labour, it has also fostered a reaction of rejection based on a fear of competition. There is clearly a time-lag between the inevitability of migration in a liberalised economy and the cultural and political acceptance of the situation. Migration is a multifaceted phenomenon. INTRODUCTION} What happened in Malaysia at the beginning of 1998 is very revealing: on January 2, the government announced the expulsion of one million migrant workers, in reaction to the job losses resulting from the “financial crisis”3 in Asia. The country was not the only one to announce such measures: Thailand and even South Korea did the same. By mid-February, Bangkok had already repatriated 30,000 illegal, mostly Burmese, foreigners in three months. In Asia, three million migrants are under threat of repatriation owing to the financial crisis which began mid-1997. On February 4, however, Malaysia did a u-turn, announcing that it was ending its policy of expulsion. Tens of millions of illegal migrants (70 per cent from Indonesia) promptly tried to enter the country, forcing the authorities to declare a state of emergency, open the camps, and repatriate them in their thousands. Why did Malaysia have a change of heart? Was it simply because the International Labour Organisation (ILO) asked it to stave off the social impact of the crisis? Unlikely. Was it because Malaysian employers feared losing cheap labour, even though the tide of public opinion could be turning against foreigners? Was it because the President of the World Bank asked it to? Was it because it didn’t want to destabilise its big neighbour Indonesia through mass repatriation? This u-turn illustrates the contradictions between the economic reasoning that leads to the search for cheap labour, wherever it comes from, the tendency to blame a country’s problems on foreigners, and the individual motives of the emigrant seeking work. It shows that migrant workers are accepted only because they serve company interests. The more companies internationalise (in their shareholdings, their markets, the origin of their inputs), the more widely they recruit. The cost of labour takes precedence over nationality. Within limits. *partie=titre THE FREE CIRCULATION OF PERSONS BECOMES THE LOGICAL COROLLARY TO THAT OF GOODS AND CAPITAL *partie=nil There is migration and migration. Although prompted by economic motives, the Europeans who migrated to America in the XIX century set out to settle and populate the country. Today’s migrants, on the contrary, usually intend to return home (even if they don’t always do so). Recent migratory flows have consisted of people seeking work. It is because they bring their labour with them that these men and women are accepted, even invited. Are current migratory movements “the human counterpart to the acceleration of the movement goods and capital, as labour flexibility becomes the rule in every country?” asks Pierre Guengant4. This would mean they are just another component of the new world economic order. Or, he asks “are they not simply the reflection of a world dominated by job insecurity and rapid change in the production process, in other words the reflection of a ‘new economic disorder’?”. Order or disorder, migration today is very different from what it was barely 30 years ago: to begin with it is more scattered and varied; flows are far less structured and organised and finally - as a logical consequence - public policy and the bodies that control migration have been overtaken by events. In parallel to the volatility of capital, which crosses borders with few controls, “international migratory flows have not only increased in quantity, they have also become highly volatile and unpredictable” sums up the World Bank in a Discussion Paper.5 In recent decades, Asia, Africa and the Arab world have become the principal points of departure for migrants, while the traditional countries of emigration, with the exception of Mexico, now play a minor role. Most migration takes place between the countries of the South. The ORSTOM estimates that there are 40 million international migrants in black Africa, including 6 million refugees.6 International migration has reached unprecedented proportions: between 1970 and 1990, an average of 6 million people changed countries each year, reaching a peak of 14.9 million in 1989. According to the United Nations department7 set up to deal with the issue, there are now nearly 130 million migrants, about 15 million of whom are refugees listed by the HCR. It is difficult to obtain reliable figures however, owing to illegal migration on the one hand, and the difficulty of defining what a migrant is on the other. The table below, published by the ILO, puts the number of people working abroad at 42 million. It also shows that in the countries of the Middle East (the only countries where the number of workers is lower than that of the number of family members accompanying them) the majority are individual migrants. “Unskilled, and often uneducated, workers(… ) represent the biggest numerical mass… ”8 Women now account for a growing proportion of migrants. Nearly half a million Sri Lanka women have emigrated to the Middle East, while there are 12 women to every one man among the inter-Asian migrants from the Philippines. The scale of international migration should not divert attention from the level of displacement within a country, which is rarely recorded. In China alone, according to the official Xinhua agency, there are 80 million internal economic migrants. Migration nowadays is of course made that much easier by better transport, but the link isn’t automatic. It is connected to an element inherent in the dominant model of the development process, which accentuates the mobility of persons and their access to other countries and cultures, breaking “traditional” ties. The theoretical debate is by no means over. Some specialists believe that the increase in international trade discourages migration: by transferring production, you avoid the transfer of labour. But that theory is challenged. It implies that the host country is able to restrict legal immigration, reduce illegal migration, and actively support foreign direct investment in migrant-sending countries.9 All these conditions are difficult to meet for States whose influence has been curtailed by globalisation. It also ignores the fact that many of the tasks immigrants are employed to perform cannot be transferred to another location because they are local by nature: cleaning, public transport, personal services… Which is why it is more accurate to look upon the volatility of capital and labour as complementary. *partie=titre THE GLOBALISATION OF LABOUR, TREATED AS A COMMODITY, IS INCREASING MIGRATION *partie=nil When people speak of globalisation they are usually thinking of capital speculation, the concentration of decision-making in the hands of a few major financial companies and the free circulation of services and capital. However, the notion of factors of production includes another element, rarely mentioned in such discussions: labour. “Globalisation is often reduced to its commercial dimension” writes Claude Pottier in Le Monde. “But what we are seeing today is not so much the intensification of international trade as the increase in the international mobility of the factors of production.” Curiously, regional markets, supposedly the precursors of the vast “single world market” have reacted very differently to this new situation. The European Common Market, which became the Community, then the Union, very quickly integrated the principle of the free (internal) circulation of persons. By contrast, the North American Free Trade Agreement maintains strict controls over migration from Mexico to the United States (see box). But socio-economic reality often goes beyond the limits the law tries to set it. Today, the city with the second largest Mexican population after Mexico city is Los Angeles. The Lisbon Group, led by Riccardo Petrella, distinguishes three stages for understanding how globalisation influences migratory flows: internationalisation, multinationalisation and globalisation11. The first is measured according to the intensity of foreign trade and population movements, the statistics for which enable the public authorities to ensure supervision and guidance. When it comes to internationalisation, the public authorities “can control population movements and can legislate on questions of citizenship, closing or opening borders as they see fit”. (p54). Multinationalisation is characterised by the relocation of resources, primarily capital and to a lesser extent labour. National borders become easier and easier to cross. As for globalisation, it is characterised by the weakening of the national public authorities. “It is difficult to identify a precise territory (be it legal, economic, technological or other) for these organisations [present throughout the world] even though they have a country of origin” (p.69). The three key words that characterise globalisation are liberalisation, privatisation and deregulation, which apply equally to the movement of populations. States resist, trying to defend that aspect of their sovereignty that consists of authorising or refusing access to their territory. But they can do less and less about it. *partie=titre MIGRATION, A GOOD DEAL *partie=nil “If wealth doesn’t come to you, then you must go where the wealth is”. Such could be the motto of the migrant worker, but also the cause of their misfortune. Analyses of what motivates migrants to leave their countries tend to concur. According to Pierre George, “economic migration is usually prompted by a deterioration in living standards in a population whose demographic growth has not been accompanied by a corresponding growth in resources. It particularly concerns the least privileged social classes.”12 The decisive factor, according to this analysis, is the situation in the country of departure, and emigration is the response. It overlaps with another analysis which places more emphasis on the demand for labour in the country of destination. In the past, and in exceptional cases (South East Asia until mid- 1997 for example), this demand was the result of an imbalance between the supply of jobs and the workforce available. In most cases, however, this analysis needs to be tempered by other factors such as the refusal of a section of a host country’s workforce to perform certain low-paid or unpleasant tasks. “The dominant phenomenon today is the temporary emigration of unskilled workers from under-developed or economically backward countries, who come to work in rapidly expanding countries whose population, with the benefit of education and vocational training, abandon manual labour for better paid jobs in industry, the services and administration” says Pierre George. In Malaysia, for example, the construction sector is dependent on a workforce that is 80 per cent foreign, the migrant workers taking the lowest paid jobs despised by Malaysian nationals. Rather than improve working conditions, employers prefer to use workers who, being poorer, are less likely to protest. Whichever view is taken, migration has a healthy future, bearing in mind that the gap in wealth and in population is steadily increasing, not only between North and South but also between regions of the South. The Lisbon Group notes that population growth will be higher in Asia and Africa than elsewhere over the next 20 years. It also notes that the world is becoming polarised geographically and socially between rich and poor. Since 1965, the share of wealth of the world’s poorest 20 per cent has fallen from 2.3 per cent to 1.4 per cent, while that of the richest 20 per cent has risen from 75 to 85 per cent. The income gap between the richest and poorest 20 per cent has doubled from 30 to 1 to 61 to 113. These are documented figures, but less is known about the internal differences within countries or regions. The US has 60 million poor, the European Union 52 million, the former USSR and the Eastern bloc between 80 and 100 million. And there is nothing to indicate that this polarisation process will change course in the next few years. There will be many people tempted to opt for emigration, therefore. And while workers are without question the victims, in being obliged to migrate just to survive, there are also benefits for their families and their country of origin. Nor are they are not the only ones: migration is a flourishing business. *partie=titre For the smugglers *partie=nil Recent observation indicates a growth in the proportion of temporary migrants. Some are seasonal workers returning regularly to the same place; this is generally the case for the rural world. Others successively travel to other places, returning in between visits to their own country. These repeated movements are a fruitful market for a booming business: the recruitment and placement agencies. In Asia, for example, they handle about 80 per cent of migration to the Arab states in the Persian Gulf. But migrants who aim to leave their country permanently also go through these agencies, if they plan to enter a country illegally. Some of these enterprises are organised: others amount to a couple of smugglers. Many flirt with illegality and rely on the complicity of civil servants to ensure their impunity. For the International Labour Organisation this activity falls within the domain of the private employment agencies. ILO Convention 96 on private employment agencies dates from 1949, and was revised in June 1997, although the revised version is not yet in force. The new text obliges States to protect migrants placed in their territory by private employment agencies. For the agencies, a code of good conduct is proposed, aimed principally at combating trafficking. While it may be useful to have such a Convention, there is scant chance of imposing it on smugglers. There have been countless incidents involving illegal migrants, where they have been left in the hold of a boat, abandoned on the side of the road, where they found the job they were promised does not exist (or is in reality prostitution), where the price they have had to pay is so exorbitant that they end up in debt and have to work illegally to repay it, or their passport has been confiscated… such cases, reported in the press, only represent the tip of the iceberg. With no visa and little money, many prospective migrants have no choice but to turn to the modern-day slave traders. In addition to the risks they run (including being sent back home if caught) it could cost them US$ 3,000 to go from the Philippines to Kuwait, between US$ 4,000 and US$6,000 from Bangladesh to Germany, and US$ 25,000 from China to the United States. The illegal traffic in labour involves more than 6 million people every year, duped and exploited by middlemen. In total, it earns the mafias that organise it some US$ 7 billion a year. *partie=titre For the families*partie=nil There is no doubt that the money sent home by migrants is a welcome addition to their income for the relatives who stayed in the country of origin. Indeed it is the main purpose of temporary and/or individual migration. What many may not realise is that rural families from countries in Central America, for example, often do their shopping in dollars. This apparent advantage does have its downside however. P.Guengant15 points out that the increase in migrants’ families’ purchasing power may prompt a demand for imported goods, which is expensive for the country; may encourage people to give up local jobs where they consider the pay too low; could lead to expenditure on prestige items, or could idealise emigration as the only solution. Qualitatively, the material constraints linked to emigration often lead to a breakdown in family life. This is felt particularly acutely when it is the woman who leaves. The government of Sri Lanka, from where 500,000 women, often married, often mothers, have emigrated, has even decided to carry out a survey into the social and economic repercussions of this situation. It is by no means certain, however, that the departure of men does not have an impact on family life. *partie=titre For the country of origin *partie=nil The emigration of workers to other countries has a dual effect, negative and positive, on the country of departure. On the one hand, it constitutes a loss of human and financial resources. It is a human loss because of the individual decision to leave, which is always a wrench emotionally, and is often taken by the more dynamic people on the job market; they could have put their dynamism to work for the benefit of their own community had the possibility existed. Again in the words of Pierre George “Migrants are individuals aged 15 to 35 who go to offer their labour in expanding economies”. The loss is also financial. Not to mention the “brain drain”17 which concerns a minority of less representative workers, the emigrants who have benefited from higher education or vocational training and whose departure represents a loss of the investment the country has made in teaching them their skills. On the other hand, there are undeniable gains for the country of departure. The advantage is twofold. First of all it brings currency into the country. In El Salvador, the remesas (remittances) , the money sent home by emigrants to their families, have become the principal source of income, far ahead of coffee exports. The one million Sri Lankan emigrants, two thirds of whom are in the Middle East, are thought to have sent some 830 million dollars back to the country in 1997. In Bangladesh too, emigration is one of the most important sources of income (nearly 1.5 billion dollars in 1997). In one of the most extreme cases, the remittances from migrant workers reached a high of 78 per cent of Yemen’s GNP in 1980. It is also not uncommon for remittances to be 25-50 per cent of the value of merchandise exports.18 And they amount to more than public development aid, which is sometimes presented as a means of keeping migrants in their home country. Secondly, in some cases (Cuba for example) emigration may help defuse a tense social situation created by unemployment and the lack of future prospects. Proof of this is the eagerness of some countries to encourage the emigration of their unemployed workers. Vietnam, for example. 12,661 Vietnamese worked abroad in 1996, and the government wants to increase this number. It has taken measures to liberalise the recruitment agency sector and to train future emigrants. The same applies to Sri Lanka, which hopes to increase emigration by 20 per cent. Thailand, which imports labour from Burma, Cambodia, Laos, etc., sends workers abroad (Malaysia… ) and it is trying to increase their number this year, despite the crisis. Elsewhere, in Guatemala for example, economists stress that the young should be taught English as “they will constitute our principal export product”. Inevitably, any labour exporting country will find itself competing on a limited market. China stresses the low wages its potential emigrants are prepared to accept in order to encourage other countries to take them, while Sri Lanka emphasises the skills of its workers, and Thailand boasts of the “good quality” of its people, who “work hard, agree to negotiate, and are tireless”. Enterprises and employers are all too happy to reap the benefits of such competition. *partie=titre The host country *partie=nil The recent trend of blaming migrants for rising unemployment in the host countries ignores the advantages they gained from immigration. After the Second World War, the industrialised countries systematically recruited migrants. Belgium for example signed agreements with Italy and Morocco. As for the United States, they signed an agreement with Mexico in 1942 called the Bracero Programme (bracero Sp. labourer) aimed at alleviating the shortage of labour in the US. Up to half a million Mexicans per year entered the United States legally under this programme. Today, even if this shortage is over the advantages for the host countries persist, thanks to the presence of a population of consumers. More than ten years ago, a study in Germany showed that sending immigrants home would result in more jobs lost than gained for country nationals, owing to the fact that migrants are also consumers (albeit on a small scale), require housing and healthcare (however poor), send their children to school. Furthermore, it is not certain that national workers would be prepared to occupy the jobs left vacant by foreigners; at least not under the same bad conditions.19 Which may explain Malaysia’s u-turn: when the expulsion measures were announced, the opposition asked whether Malaysian nationals would agree to take on the migrants jobs, or whether some sectors would find themselves short of workers. A supply of cheap labour is an advantage for enterprises, while at the same time it affects the competitiveness of national products, demography (in a country where the local population is ageing) and some macro-economic indicators. Hence the headline from the Swiss press agency InfoSud: “Panic spreads across health, hotel and building sectors, where contribution of foreign workforce is essential”. The story behind the headline was that following the threat to restrict the number of family members joining migrant workers, the Federation of Immigrant Associations in Switzerland predicted that half a million migrants would leave. Furthermore, “Industrialised countries whose natural rate of growth is now close to zero are wondering whether it would not be in their interests to hold on to part of their immigrant population, at least the most adaptable members, despite the effects of the crisis on the labour market and the risk that it could lead to the creation of ‘ghettos’”, writes Pierre George. *partie=titre MIGRANTS, VICTIMS OF EXPLOITATION *partie=nil “Migrants are usually employed in the least skilled or the most unpleasant tasks(… )They earn less than their indigenous counterparts for the same work. They are the victims of frequent discrimination when it comes to hiring, promotion, social security and job security. When the employment market contracts, immigrants are the first to lose their jobs.”22 Migrants are the victims of many forms of discrimination and exploitation. Some highly publicised cases such as that of the young Filipino maid Sarah Balabagan have drawn attention to domestic work, the most common occupation for the many Asian women who emigrate to the Middle East. Other stories of exploitation that have made the headlines include that of the deaf and dumb Mexican workers in New York, of the maids shut away in embassies, or the textile sweatshops hidden in the heart of big Western cities. What emerges from these dramatic cases is that some categories of migrants are more at risk than others, in the countries of both North and South. Maids, because of their isolation, their dependency, and their constant presence at the work place. Illegal migrants who are often transported and housed in inhuman conditions, and are unable to defend themselves against employer abuse for fear of expulsion. Temporary workers too. Anxious to put money aside from their earnings to send home to their families, and to appear successful when they return home, they live a hand-to-mouth existence in the host country. Temporary immigration is reassuring for the receiving countries, which appreciate the flexibility of this mobile workforce. It also leads to abuse of these workers who are obliged to accept low wages, bad working conditions and accommodation, face the risk of accident. “Normal” jobs in industry, commerce or the service sector are not above criticism either. Speaking about immigrants in Thailand, Guy Thijs, ILO sub-regional coordinator for Asia, explains that for them “there is no minimum wage, no social security, no organised protection” 23 Excessive or “broken” working hours, low wages, late payment, unaware of their rights… the dream can quickly turn to a nightmare. There are ILO Conventions on equal treatment, notably Convention 97 (1948), and a United Nations Convention on the protection of migrant workers and their families, Convention 158 (1990). Adopted with great pomp in 1990 the Convention has still not received the number of ratifications needed for its application (only 8 countries out of the required 20 have officially ratified it). But despite these, not all States are blameless in their attitude towards the attacks on the human rights and dignity of the men and women obliged to seek work outside their own country. In the case of Saudi Arabia, for example, Human Rights Watch considers the labour legislation itself allows for such abuse.24 Even where there is no abuse, even where they are legally established, migrants are second class citizens, usually deprived of any voting rights. They are accepted provided they remain different “As a worker, the immigrant is useful, precisely because s/he occupies a socially marginal position”, write Bastenier and Dassetto25. Trade unions are usually the exception as migrant workers are considered first and foremost workers and may vote and stand for election. *partie=titre MIGRATION, A THREAT TO SOCIAL PROGRESS *partie=nil The neo-liberal economy is based on the market, on the law of supply and demand. Logically, if there is competition between workers owing to an excess of supply over demand, the price of labour falls. This price consists of both the worker’s salary and their working conditions. Hence Claude Pottier's conclusion in Le Monde: “In the industrialised countries, immigration weakens workers’ negotiating strength vis a vis employers.” This is not the fault of the immigrant workers, it is because globalisation “places workers throughout the world in direct competition with each other, driving employment conditions and pay downwards.” The traditional method of “divide and rule” is replaced here by “open (borders) and rule”. Mass migration combined with the declining power of national States has decompartmentalised national markets for the benefit of a globalised market. This is no bad thing in itself; national borders are largely artificial. But historically, workers’ social rights have been won within the national framework, with the fight carried out within a particular context, and based on that particular balance of power. Globalisation transposes this power relationship to the world level. And despite the work of international and continental trade union organisations, the business world dominates at this level. Paradoxically, to play devil’s advocate, there could be one positive outcome (but only one) to sending immigrants home from a country such as Thailand, for example. If country nationals have to take on the low paid, low status jobs abandoned by the migrants, employers may have to improve wages and working conditions. But this would require solidarity and a balance of power in the workers’ favour - and therefore a level of organisation - which is unlikely in the present globalised context. The most likely outcome is a levelling downwards. Why not have an International Immigration Agreement, which would protect migrants just as other agreements protect investments, services or goods? No doubt because the climate is not ripe; on the contrary: “Enterprises demand that the policies and laws of a State promote their freedom of action, particularly as regards the regulation of the labour market”27. Some international conventions do exist at the ILO and in the United Nations. It is a question of making sure they are applied. *partie=titre OUTDATED POLICIES AND ATTITUDES *partie=nil In Asia and the United States in particular, but also elsewhere, a large proportion of immigrant workers are illegal. This does not usually cause many problems, provided the workers are not perceived as being in competition with country nationals on the labour market. The illegal workers are in fact meeting an economic need for enterprises, in terms of labour costs. But as soon as tensions are felt, as in Asia recently but also in Europe and the United States, their illegal situation is used as an argument to exclude these workers. Two conflicting lines of logic seem to be in operation at the same time: the logic governing labour costs in a capitalist economy, which encourages the hiring of foreign workers, and the logic that approaches nationality at the political level. At the same time, there is the neo-liberal economic argument, which calls for cheap labour, in conflict with the collective psychological tendency to use foreigners as scapegoats. These conflicting lines of reasoning can sometimes be employed by the same person. Ronald Reagan, for example, strongly advocated neo-liberal economics, yet decided to impose strict controls on the entry of Latin American migrants into the United States. Sompong Nakornsri, a Thai entrepreneur, speaking of the plans to send home hundreds of thousands of migrants from Thailand commented: “The Minister of Labour wondered whether employers will find enough Thai workers after sending the migrants home.”28 Anxious to keep its population happy, however, Thailand confirmed in mid-March that 800,000 illegal workers had to leave the country. It even foresaw sanctions for employers who did not comply with the decision. At the same time, the government of Hong Kong, perhaps to be more realistic, or at least less bound by democratic constraints, announced that despite unemployment and poverty it would “import” new immigrants for the construction industry, against the will of the local trade union confederation. *partie=titre THE TRADE UNION RESPONSE *partie=nil Trade unions are calling on governments to provide more development aid to the developing countries to assist job creation, so that workers are not forced to emigrate. Governments should provide the same level of protection and the same advantages for workers moving from one country to another and for those moving within the same country. The trade unions, at both the international and national level, are mobilising throughout the world to urge their governments to sign up to and ratify the international legal instruments on the protection of migrant workers. (see list of legal instruments in Appendix I). The trade unions should also adopt a trade union charter for migrant workers, organise campaigns against racism and xenophobia, and organise migrant workers, giving them special support in view of their serious disadvantages. In some cases, such as Italy, the trade unions have for a long time been carrying out campaigns and specific action in an attempt to organise and assist migrants. At present such action is one of the spearheads of the trade union struggle in the United States, where there are more than 2 million agricultural workers, principally Mexican immigrants, who are not affiliated to a trade union. The United Farm Workers (UFW), which under the leadership of its founder Cesar Chavez, came to prominence in the sixties by successfully organising vineyard workers in California, has managed to put agricultural labour back at the heart of the US labour and social movement. This offensive in the agricultural sector symbolises the regaining of lost ground for the American trade unions. And the choice of this specific sector is highly symbolic. To defend California’s seasonal workers is to defend the poorest, the socially excluded, a new immigrant proletariat very different from the traditional membership of the US trade unions. Migrant workers employed as domestic maids, who are even more difficult to organise and often the most exploited, are also the target of organising campaigns, despite the difficulty in penetrating the immigrant community these women belong to. In Australia, through the Australian clothing workers’ union (CATU), in Canada through the women clothing workers’ union (ILGWU) and in the Netherlands through the women’s union affiliated to the national centre FNV, trade unions have set about establishing contact with these women workers. In all three cases, they took a three-pronged approach: establishing contact, collecting information to sensitise opinion and pressing for a strengthening of migrant domestic workers’ rights. As the ICFTU Women’s Committee recommended (see recommendations in Appendix II), the trade unions should take concrete action to forge alliances with the various actors concerned, particularly the NGOs and churches present on the spot. The ICFTU for example is involved in a broad coalition of NGOs and trade unions in a project developed by SOLIDAR and supported by the European Commission, to set up a network of migrant women domestic workers in Europe. *partie=titre CONCLUSION: “Are migrants men and women, or just labour?” *partie=nil “The growing economic and demographic gap separating the industrialised and developing countries can only serve to reinforce migratory phenomena. These therefore constitute a structural component of the contemporary world economy.” All the signs are that despite the xenophobic reactions it provokes, migration will continue to be an unavoidable fact of life. Professor Appelyard, editor of the International Migrations magazine is among many who believe that the phenomenon will continue to grow, particularly between countries of the South. Opposition to international migration in the name of national sovereignty raises fundamental questions both of a political nature (restoring the role of politics, weakened by a globalised business world) and in terms of economic efficiency. There is also an ethical aspect. How can it be acceptable, for example, that in California only US citizens have the right to social security benefits, when these are financed by all workers, national citizens or otherwise, regular or irregular workers? Why is an immigrant family which lives and pays its taxes in a country, like its indigenous neighbours, deprived of citizenship? Can the workers that were sent for yesterday, because they were needed, be thrown away when there is no more need for them, like an old tool? Are migrants men and women, or just labour? The trade union movement has only one answer to all these questions, which can be summed up in one word: solidarity.